Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, I am pleased to appear here today. My testimony
is based on research that the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) has conducted at the
Committee's request concerning automated teller machine (ATM) fees and the state of
competition in markets related to ATMs. Several findings have emerged from that research:
INTRODUCTION
Most automated teller machines in the United States are connected to one or more computer
networks that let depositors access their accounts virtually anywhere. No longer must depositors
hunt for an ATM connected to "their" bank to get cash from their account. However, ATM
owners, which are principally banks but increasingly include nonbanks, have begun to impose a
fee for that convenience. (In this testimony, the term "bank" encompasses all institutions that
both take deposits and make loans, including commercial banks, savings banks, savings and
loans, and credit unions.)
The perception among cardholders that they are often being charged twice for ATM
transactions--once by their own bank and once by the owner of the ATM--has fueled
cardholders' ire. Meanwhile, federal policymakers have expressed concern about how ATM fees
may be affecting concentration and competition in both the banking industry and the market for
ATM networks, which connect the fleets of ATMs owned by various banks.
CBO's report, which is being released today, examines the structure of the fees associated with
ATM transactions as well as the status of competition among ATM owners and among ATM
networks. A further focus of the paper is how such competition interacts with competition
among banking institutions.
In my testimony, as in the CBO report generally, the term "surcharge" refers to fees imposed on
the cardholder by the ATM owner, whether the owner is a bank or nonbank. Some analysts use
the term "surcharge" to refer only to fees imposed by ATM owners that are financial institutions.
CBO follows general industry practice, which disregards ownership of the ATM and refers to all
such fees as surcharges.
HISTORY OF SURCHARGES
After the decision by the national networks, many regional networks that had previously banned
surcharges quickly lifted their prohibitions, presumably to avoid losing members. ATM owners
quickly took advantage of the end of the bans. Current surveys indicate that between two-thirds
and three-quarters of all banks now impose surcharges on ATM transactions by cardholders
whose accounts are carried at a different bank--so-called foreign transactions.
ATMs AND SHARED ATM NETWORKS: BACKGROUND INFORMATION
The Rise and Consolidation of Shared Regional ATM Networks
When banks first started installing ATMs, they quickly found that they could not individually
provide all of the access to ATMs that cardholders desired. In response, the banks formed
coalitions and developed state and regional networks to which virtually all ATMs today are
connected.
As banks have spread geographically, increasingly crossing state boundaries, so, too, have the
shared networks. Furthermore, like the banks they serve, the larger networks have in many cases
taken over smaller networks whose regions they have moved into. As a result, the number of
shared regional networks has dropped substantially over the past 10 to 15 years, from over 150 in
the early 1980s to less than 50 today. And industry analysts expect further consolidation. In
essence, the consolidation of the regional networks reflects--perhaps in an exaggerated
way--consolidation in the banking industry.
The Proliferation of ATMs
Consolidation of the shared regional networks coincides with rapid growth in the number of ATMs, which have increased from fewer than 100,000 units in the early 1990s to over 165,000 today (see Figure 1). Since the number of ATM transactions has not risen as rapidly as the number of ATMs, the number of transactions per ATM has fallen.
SOURCE:
Congressional Budget Office using data from the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System and the Debit Card Directory, 1998 Edition (New York:
Faulkner & Gray, 1997), p. 20.
NOTE: ATM = automated teller machine.
Most of the recent increase in the number of ATMs has come from extending their reach away
from banks and into new corners of the American landscape (convenience stores, shopping malls,
and so forth). ATMs located off bank premises account for a large majority of the growth since
1994. However, most ATMs are still located at banks.
The Fee Structure in Shared ATM Networks
Five general classes of fees structure the relationships in an ATM system (see Table 1). The first
three--membership, switch, and interchange fees--are set by the ATM network. The foreign fee
is set by the card-issuing financial institution and the surcharge by the ATM owner. An ATM
owner pays a membership fee to belong to an ATM network; such fees range from hundreds to
thousands of dollars per year or per month. Card-issuing banks pay a so-called switch fee for
each transaction made by their customers--usually ranging from 2.5 cents to 12 cents--to the
network itself. Card-issuing banks pay the interchange fee to the ATM owner for each
transaction made by their customers. For cash withdrawals, interchange fees typically range
from 20 to 60 cents. Cardholders pay the foreign fee, which usually averages from $1.00 to $1.30, to their own bank when they use a foreign ATM (one owned by another bank). Cardholders may also be required to pay a user surcharge to the ATM owner. Those fees average from $0.50 to $1.50 but may be higher in some locations. The combination of the last two fees--the foreign fee and the surcharge--constitutes the so-called double-charging that is at the heart of many consumer complaints.
TABLE 1. ATM FEES | ||||
Fee | Who Pays It? | Who Receives It? | Who Sets It? | Range |
Network Membershipa | Card-issuing bank | Network | Network | $0 - $125,000 |
Switchb | Card-issuing bank | Network | Network | 2.5¢ - 12¢ |
Interchangeb | Card-issuing bank | ATM owner | Network | 20¢ - 60¢c |
Foreign or Userb | Cardholder | Card-issuing bank | Card-issuing bank | $0 - $2.50 |
Surchargeb | Cardholder | ATM owner | ATM owner | $0 - $3.00 |
SOURCE: Congressional Budget Office based on the Debit Card Directory, 1998 Edition (New York: Faulkner & Gray, 1997), and Government Accounting Office, Automated Teller Machines: Survey Results Indicate Banks' Surcharge Fees Have Increased (April 1998). | ||||
NOTE: ATM = automated teller machine. | ||||
a. The membership fee is usually paid either monthly or annually. | ||||
b. This fee is paid per transaction. | ||||
c. The range stated is for a cash withdrawal. Interchange fees vary for different types of transactions. For example, the interchange fee is usually higher for a deposit transaction than for a balance inquiry. |
BANKING COMPETITION AND THE REGIONAL ATM NETWORKS
Declining Network Switch Fees
The fees charged by networks for their own activities--that is, switch fees--have been falling,
not rising. Industry-compiled data on the switch fees of 10 of the largest ATM networks show
that the networks lowered their average reported switch fee on ATM transactions by 22 percent
between 1993 and 1997. In 1993, the average ATM switch fee was 8.5 cents; it had fallen to 6.7
cents by 1997.
Although the switch fees that networks charged all institutions were reduced by the same
amount, the fees that they charged larger institutions went down by substantially more in
percentage terms than did the fees imposed on smaller institutions. The reason is that the ATM
switch fee structure of many networks is tiered: a card issuer with many transactions pays a
lower fee per transaction than a card issuer with relatively few transactions. (Generally, CBO
assumes that large institutions will have more transactions than small ones because large banks
have more depositors.) The median fee declined by 1.5 cents per transaction for both large- and
small-tier institutions. But because the large institutions were paying a lower fee to begin with,
their percentage reduction was larger than the percentage reduction for the small institutions.
CBO has been unable to determine whether the tiered fee structure is justified by the costs that
the networks incur.
Increasing Relative Interchange Fees
The regional networks play a role in ensuring that the fees going to ATM owners remain
high--in particular, the interchange fee paid by a card-issuing bank to the institution that owns
the ATM. Because bigger banks play a disproportionate role in the shared regional networks and
own a sizable fraction of all ATMs connected to even the largest such networks, they may exert
their influence to keep interchange fees high.
Consequently, despite a drop in costs in the electronics and telecom-munications markets,
interchange fees in nominal terms have remained stable or have risen since the mid-1980s. In
actuality, however, the stability seen for the fee suggests an increase in the interchange fee
relative to general costs and would thus represent increased profits for ATM owners.
The shared networks argue that they have difficulty adjusting the fees once they have been set.
They note that although equipment and telecommunications costs have decreased substantially,
more ATMs are now located off bank premises and so cost more to service. Another weakness
in the argument that networks are keeping interchange fees artificially high is that this pattern of
stable interchange fees dates back to a period before substantial network consolidation, when
networks presumably were more competitive than they are today.
Decreasing Use of Shared Networks
At the same time that total ATM transactions have been rising, the number of transactions
handled by shared regional networks has fallen, both in absolute terms and as a share of all ATM
transactions. Foreign ATM transactions have dropped somewhat since the widespread
introduction of surcharges in 1996. (Monthly foreign ATM transactions in 1997 were 2 percent
lower than in 1996.) Considering that total ATM transactions have continued to rise, that decline
is all the more telling--and all the sharper when contrasted with the healthy rise that preceded it.
(Foreign ATM transactions had been rising at a rate of 9 percent per year for the three years
before 1996.)
Simultaneously with the drop in transactions handled by the shared networks, banks' own
networks have increased in importance. The vast majority of cardholders wish to avoid
surcharges and thus increasingly use only their bank's ATMs rather than those of other banks on
the network. Moreover, given the relative shift in prices, the prominence of the banks' networks
would be expected, even without the surcharges. Shared ATM networks were created when
ATMs were few and expensive. As the machines have become cheaper to own and operate, the
level of investment needed by the bank to service its customers and maintain its market share has
fallen. That change alone would suggest a relative shift in the use of the bank's own network
compared with the shared networks, but growth in the size of the regional banks exaggerates that
shift even further.
COMPETITION AMONG ATM OWNERS
The development of the ATM market cannot be viewed separately from changes that are
occurring in the financial services industry generally. Most important, the industry is rapidly
consolidating. Banks, thrifts, and other financial services firms are merging, which reduces the
number of firms even as they increase their capacity to provide services to cardholders and other
depositors.
Competition Among Banks
All other things being equal, a bank with more ATMs is more valuable to customers than a bank
with fewer machines, especially now that surcharges have become more widespread.
Consequently, ATMs and ATM fees form part of a bank's strategy to attract customers. For
example, most banks will not impose surcharges on their own customers for fear of driving them
away. However, large banks with large numbers of proprietary ATMs typically find it to their
strategic advantage to impose high surcharges for foreign transactions. By contrast, in response
to the spread of surcharges, an increasing number of smaller and medium-sized banks--banks
that presumably have fewer ATMs to offer their customers--have had to drop the foreign fees
they were charging their cardholders who used other banks' ATMs, presumably in response to
cardholders' complaints at being double-charged. In 1996, only 20 percent of banks did not have
foreign fees. By 1997, 33 percent of banks charged no foreign fees on cash withdrawals.
What effect do ATM surcharges have on the ability of banks to attract and retain deposits? One
way to answer that question is to compare the experience of banking institutions in the eight
states that passed laws either prohibiting network surcharge bans or explicitly permitting ATM
surcharging by 1995 with the experience of banks in the rest of the United States. If ATM
surcharging induced people to move their accounts to banks that owned large numbers of ATMs,
one would expect to see a greater increase in the concentration of deposits in banks in those
states allowing surcharging than in the rest of the United States during the same time frame. And
a greater-than-average increase in concentration has, indeed, resulted. However, the states
allowing surcharging started from a lower level of bank deposit concentration than did the nation
as a whole. Consequently, the data are not conclusive with respect to the change that has
occurred.
Even before the nationwide spread of ATM surcharges, big banks were growing at the expense
of small banks. In 1991, commercial banks with $1 billion or more in assets held 67 percent of
all deposits: in 1995, they held 72 percent, and in 1997, their share was 76 percent. The smallest
commercial banks, those with assets of $100 million or less, experienced shrinkage in their share
of deposits nationally, which went from 12 percent in 1991 to 9 percent in 1995 and 7 percent in
1997. Moreover, the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act took effect in
the last quarter of 1995. The act expanded the ability of banks and bank holding companies to
operate across state boundaries and may have contributed to the climbing rate of concentration in
the industry. Thus, it is difficult to disentangle the effects of ATM fees from the preexisting
trend of industry consolidation.
Competition Among All ATM Owners
ATM owners generally have to balance several factors in their calculations regarding both the
number of ATMs in which to invest and the charges they need to impose. As more ATMs are
deployed, especially by new entrants to the market, competition may force fees to drop.
Nevertheless, some ATM deployers may be able to continue to charge high fees in certain market
segments. (Market segments may be based on location, such as airports or recreation areas, or on
cardholders' willingness to pay.)
The increasing number of ATMs and the decreasing number of transactions per machine suggest
that high ATM surcharges may not be sustainable. If simple supply and demand were at work in
the ATM market, the entry of nonbank deployers in particular should undermine high and
increasing surcharges. But a large part of the market response to ATM surcharges is exhibited in
changes in frequency and patterns of use, not in changes in price. Cardholders typically arrange
their affairs so that most of the time, they do not pay surcharges at all. Thus, firms that surcharge
see a drop-off in the number of their foreign transactions--but usually not by enough to make
them lift the surcharge. Nonbanks have every incentive to surcharge because all of their
transactions are foreign transactions and surcharging is the primary way that they make money
from their investment. To ensure their profits, nonbanks may focus on placing ATMs in
locations where people may be more willing to pay surcharges for the sake of convenience or
because they have fewer alternatives for getting cash.
In sum, widespread surcharging is a recent phenomenon, and the market is still adjusting.
Cardholders may discover that competitive pressures are operating on surcharges and foreign
fees as the market matures over the next few years. Another possibility is that surcharges may
remain in place even as average total cardholder fees--the total of foreign fees plus
surcharges--drop. The potential for that outcome derives from the segmentation in the market
and the fact that foreign fees and surcharges are set independently by two different market
participants.
CONCLUSIONS
The current flux in the ATM market is the result not only of the advent of ATM surcharging but
of shifts in other charges associated with ATMs and in usage patterns. For example, foreign fees
are dropping in some cases, and the average number of transactions per ATM has started to
decline. In such unsettled circumstances, the effects of any legislation or regulatory change may
be difficult to determine in advance and could produce unintended effects.
Home | Menu | Links | Info | Chairman's Page